Cash Vs In-kind
However, the message is also that use of
technology without sufficient penetration
may actually do more damage to the credibility of the technological innovation rather
than help streamline delivery of subsidies in a better way
.... A policy initiative in India
Cash
transfers are the new mantra for resolving all the problems that plague service
delivery in India. However, cash transfers are neither new (scholarships,
pensions and even NREGA payments are all cash transfers) nor does the much hyped
roll-out of Direct Benefit Transfers through Aadhar in 21 districts
involve any scheme which is not already a cash transfer. The debate really
is about the future possibility of converting existing in-kind subsidies such
as food, fertiliser and fuel into cash. Theoretically, there is nothing wrong
in a system of cash subsidy delivery
so long as beneficiaries can
purchase the equivalent amount of goods and services through the cash.
Proponents of cash transfers see this as a magic bullet not because this
improves outcomes in terms of the stated purpose of subsidies but because it
may cure problems in present service delivery which at present is plagued with
serious leakages. Another argument in favour of cash transfers is that current in-kind
subsidies are market distorting and the belief that therefore cash
transfers may be more
efficient.
Unfortunately,
the debate on cash versus in-kind transfers has not been backed by sufficient empirical
evidence. The case in favour of cash transfers is usually built on the grounds
that the existing public institutions involved in kind transfers are inefficient both in terms of reaching intended beneficiaries and in the costs they incur for whatever they deliver. Such
perceptions are backed most often by reference to the Public Distribution
System (PDS) where leakages are undoubtedly high and also complaints abound
regarding functioning of the Food Corporation of India and the targeted public
distribution system. However, the argument that a large part of the grain is used
by the non-poor is a complex argument. A lot of the problems in this regard are
because of the faulty
selection of beneficiaries and
also due to arbitrary capping of number
of beneficiaries at the state level-problems
which neither cash-transfers nor Aadhar will resolve. In fact, there is now
strong evidence that states which have universalised their PDS have also managed
to eliminate leakages to a large extent. The message from the successful states
is that a reduction in food prices has led to elimination of leakages. Finally,
this has also been made possible by the successful adoption of basic technology
such as GPS and SMS in streamlining the function of PDS. But then these
are problems which not only require innovative thinking but also a strong
political will to eliminate leakages in the functioning of PDS. Similarly, there is now sufficient evidence that the
FCI is not as inefficient as
it is made out to be. Except for 2004-05, for most years for which data is
available, economic cost of FCI is in fact lower than the prevailing market
prices. This is despite the fact that FCI not only pays full MSP and taxes that
the private sector often does not and incurs much higher costs on account of more
long distance transportation and much larger storage obligations than that of
the private sector.
Perhaps
more importantly, many of the arguments against the PDS ignore two basic
facts. First that those who use the PDS complain less than those who
do not (a 2010 NCAER study shows satisfaction levels of about 80% among actual beneficiaries in most States other than Bihar) and second
that PDS does provide real purchasing power to the poor, particularly those at
the bottom of the distribution. Our own analysis of consumption data from the NSS
clearly shows that PDS alone accounts for a substantial part of poverty
reduction between 2004- 05 and 2009-10, particularly if one uses inequality
sensitive measures such as the squared poverty gap. Moreover, there is clear evidence
that those consuming from the PDS are the only group of households which have
seen an increase in calorie consumption. This
is significant considering that there
has been a secular decline in calorie consumption of the population in the last
three decades. Although,
it is difficult to measure the
impact on nutritional outcomes due to PDS consumption, the evidence on
calorie consumption is sufficient to suggest that if the purpose is reducing
levels of malnutrition, then PDS seems to have had an impact. While this
evidence is clear, there is no counterfactual to test it with what would have
happened with cash transfers. But a
comparison of those with similar consumption expenditure level after adjusting for
implicit income transfer of PDS consuming households does show that households
with PDS access are likely to have significantly more calorie consumption and
that a rupee transferred through PDS leads to about twice the increase in calorie
consumption than a rupee given otherwise without access to PDS. In other words,
if the choice is made between in kind transfers and cash transfers, then
same amount of transfer in case of PDS increases calorie consumption by twice compared to cash transfer.
While this is convincing evidence of superiority
of in kind transfers compared to cash transfers, there is some merit in
continuing cash transfers for the vulnerable groups. This in fact has been the
case in India where cash transfers such as social pensions (widow pension, disability
pension and old-age pension) have been helpful in enabling households to access
basic necessities including those from the PDS. But what makes these cash
transfers important is the fact that these are not substitutes of existing
in kind subsidies which are meant to improve outcomes of a particular kind of
deprivation. This in fact is also the lesson from the Latin American
countries which are seen as successful role models for cash transfers. Not,
only the level of deprivation in each dimension in these Latin American countries
much lower than India, these countries use cash transfers only to supplement
other benefits and universal
provision of basic necessities. In
fact most of these cash transfers including the famous Bolsa Familia are programmes
which give cash incentives to encourage these households to access the basic in-kind
services already in place. These are not
a substitute for the government’s commitment to provide universal basic
services. But these conditionalities are important and useful when there is
abundant supply of these, unlike the Indian case where there is hardly any
supply of the basic amenities and services.
Fortunately
the recent announcement of Direct
Benefit Transfer (DBT) cannot yet
be seen as a move towards cash transfers. Cash transfers have existed as means
of poverty alleviation for long in India and the current move is at best an
attempt to streamline the delivery of these existing cash benefits to the
beneficiaries in a different manner. Most of the schemes (mainly scholarships) which will benefit from the DBT are already cash transfers and most of them
are also direct in the sense that they are delivered to beneficiaries’ bank account directly or through cheques. Incidentally, there is
no scheme of the Ministry of Rural Development which is the nodal ministry for
most of the social pensions.
The
only addition to this scheme of things is the introduction of one more layer of verification and that is the aadhar. While this in itself is not problematic,
there are concerns that the DBT may be a costly way of approaching the problem.
Since the penetration of aadhar numbers itself is at a low level in most of
the districts selected for rollout
in the first phase, there is genuine apprehension that even the existing
beneficiaries may face delays and rejections due to non-availability of aadhar
numbers or due to rejection of biometric ids. However, this is not much of a concern since majority of
the programmes which reach the poor such as social pensions are not yet covered
by the programme. Most of these transfers do not involve any significant amount of ghost beneficiaries
and there is limited utility
of linking these with aadhar numbers. However, But even for the remaining, the
non-availability of adequate infrastructure and safeguards has meant that the initial
rollout has been limited to only 21 districts as against the proposed 51
districts. According to reports, this will cover at most 2 lakh beneficiaries.
Significantly, the government has so far maintained that there is no plan of
shifting in kind subsidies such as food and fertiliser to cash.
Clearly,
the only objective of the new announcement is to test the efficacy of aadhar as an authentication tool. Such pilots are
already underway in Jharkhand (MGNREGA), Karnataka (LPG) and Andhra Pradesh
(food) for more than a year. The results so far have not been very encouraging even
after a year except in the pilot at East Godavari district of Andhra Pradesh.
However, it is also worth mentioning that the East Godavari experiment is the
only one which does
not deliver benefits in cash. It
delivers benefits in kind. But two
other reasons why the East Godavari experiment performs better than the
Karnataka and Jharkhand experiment are the fact that the East Godavari
experiment is universal (for all
beneficiaries without
targeting) and it has aadhar penetration of more than 99% among the beneficiaries. In fact, given the level of banking penetration
in East Godavari, even with all these safeguards, a system of cash delivery would
have met the same fate as that of its counterparts in Karnataka and Jharkhand.
In
fact, the learning from the yearlong experiments clearly point towards the
necessity of universal coverage (or quasi universal) but also the fact that the
system of aadhar authentication works only when the coverage is more than 99%.
While these two are necessary conditions for the system to work, the results
also show that the technology itself is
neutral to whether the benefits are
given in kind or in cash. The reasons are quite obvious. While aadhar is a
proof of identity, it is no substitute for proof of eligibility which is
essential in a targeted regime of benefit delivery. The hurry with which
the government has moved towards making aadhar compulsory for transfer of benefits does not show any seriousness in either
improving service delivery or better identification of those truly in need. On the other hand, it appears
to be a back door manoeuvre to increase the aadhar penetration in the absence
of necessary legal sanction from the parliament.
The
big message from the available evidence as well as the pilots is clearly that
the DBT is neither a magic wand nor is it undesirable. However, the message is
also that use of technology without sufficient penetration may actually do more
damage to the credibility of the technological innovation rather than help
streamline delivery of subsidies in a better way. On the other hand, there is
clear evidence that any such move should remain restricted to existing cash benefits alone. Attempts to convert in kind subsidies
to cash subsidy may prove more seriously detrimental in the absence of adequate
infrastructure such as availability of banking and other infrastructure.
But even if banking and other infrastructure is put in place, and the
purpose is to improve nutritional outcomes, cash transfers are unlikely to be a
substitute for the PDS. The problem here is hugely behavioural with even
poor people spending less on food than on other things to keep up with neighbours.
The way out is reforming the existing PDS not dismantling it. But even here
cash transfers and Aadhar may have a role if cash can be transferred to the PDS
outlet at the point of delivery. In short, much more thinking is required to
use the technology properly.
Dr. Himanshu Abhijit Sen is Assistant Professor, Centre for the Study of Regional
Development, JNU. Prof. Abhijit Sen, is Member, Planning Commission.
0 comments:
Post a Comment